The question of the wealth of nations has been at the center of economics for more than two centuries. There is now increasing focus, both in academic and policy realms, on the entrepreneur as the driver of economic growth. For policymakers, the focus on entrepreneurship has been a recent phenomenon. In 1998, the OECD launched a program, "Fostering Entrepreneurship," to better understand the role of entrepreneurs in the economy at large. Governments throughout the world have launched various initiatives designed to promote entrepreneurship and economic growth (Reynolds, Hay, and Camp 1999). The importance of the entrepreneur in economic development has also been realized by the key international aid organizations. The World Bank, the U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID), and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) have all commissioned studies and undertaken initiatives to understand and promote entrepreneurship.
Although many articles in the academic literature recognize the importance of the entrepreneur (e.g, Kirzner 1973; Left 1979; Baumol 1990, 2002), this topic has not received the widespread attention that it deserves. This lack of focus results primarily from the fact that it is difficult to formally model entrepreneurial behavior. The entrepreneur has been characterized as an innovator (Schumpeter 1950, 1961), an arbitrageur (Kirzner 1973), one who bets on ideas (Brenner 1985, Mokyr 1990), and as a forecaster and capitalist (Rothbard 1963). Each of these interconnected elements undoubtedly plays an important role in the notion of entrepreneurship. However, for the purpose of our analysis, we are most interested in understanding entrepreneurship as alertness to and the seizing of profit opportunities.
It is typically assumed that a lack of economic growth means that there is a shortage of entrepreneurs and, more generally, "entrepreneurial spirit." This view, however, overlooks the essence of entrepreneurial alertness. Understanding alertness to profit opportunities as the central tenet of entrepreneurship makes clear that a lack of progress results from a lack of profit opportunities tied to activities that yield economic growth--not from a lack of entrepreneurial activity. Although it is usual to think that the existence of profit opportunities necessarily leads to economic growth, this may not be the case. Different institutional contexts create higher payoffs to differing sets of activities that may possibly lead to economic growth but may also lead to economic stagnation or even retrogression. In short, profitability is not synonymous with positive economic growth. Instead, what is important is the type of activity that yields profit opportunities to alert entrepreneurs.
Our core thesis is as follows: Institutionally dependent payoffs determine the direction of entrepreneurial alertness and efforts. In order to understand the plight of developing countries, it is critical to understand that it is not a lack of entrepreneurship that is the problem, but rather the institutional context directing entrepreneurial activities toward perverse ends. Specifically, some institutional regimes channel entrepreneurial activity into economically destructive avenues, while other frameworks direct this activity in a way that creates wealth.
We distinguish between productive, unproductive, and evasive entrepreneurship. After exploring this distinction, we present a general framework for considering the key institutions that constitute the social order. Original evidence from fieldwork in Romania is provided to support our claims. (1) We conclude with some general policy guidelines regarding entrepreneurship, institutional regimes, and economic growth.
Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Evasive
Entrepreneurs are present in every country and every cultural setting. We observe different outcomes from entrepreneurial activities because activities yielding the highest payoffs vary across societies. In countries with low growth, it is not that entrepreneurs are not acting. Rather, these countries are stymied by the presence of entrepreneurial profit opportunities counter to economic progress.
A complete theory of entrepreneurship must provide some understanding of factors that direct the alertness of individual entrepreneurs. In other words, entrepreneurs can engage in productive activities resulting in economic growth or they can engage in unproductive and evasive activities resulting in economic stagnation or retrogression. Baumol was the first to make the distinction between productive and unproductive entrepreneurship (1990, 2002: 59-61).
Productive activities--arbitrage and innovation--constitute the very essence of economic growth and progress. When engaging in productive activities, the entrepreneur has a dual role. The first involves discovering previously unexploited profit opportunities. This pushes the economy from an economically (and technologically) inefficient point toward the economically (and technologically) efficient production point. The second role takes place via innovation. Innovation results in a more efficient use of resources shifting the entire production possibility frontier (PPF) outward (Kirzner 1985). This shift represents the essence of economic growth--an increase in real output due to increases in real productivity. In short, productive entrepreneurship encompasses those activities that benefit both the entrepreneur and society at large. The entrepreneur benefits himself by benefiting others.
In contrast, unproductive activities include those that benefit the entrepreneur but harm society in general. Examples include crime, rent seeking, and other behaviors that destroy existing resources. In the case of unproductive entrepreneurship, it is possible that innovation is taking place, but these activities do not shift the PPF outward. As an example, consider new techniques for engaging in rent seeking. While such techniques lead to increased profit for the entrepreneur undertaking the activity, they result in a loss for society as a whole.
To productive and unproductive activities, we can add a third category: evasive entrepreneurship. Evasive activities include the expenditure of resources and efforts in evading the legal system or in avoiding the unproductive activities of other agents. Tax evasion is one readily apparent example of evasive activities, as are bribes paid to regulators or inspectors used to evade onerous regulations. Both productive and unproductive entrepreneurship involve the creation of deadweight losses--in both cases resources are expended solely to affect the distribution of existing wealth.
One of the central claims of this article is that institutionally dependent payoffs determine the direction of entrepreneurial alertness. Before moving on, we provide a general framework of institutions. In order to gain analytical traction, we consider three general formal institutional categories--economic, political, and legal--underlying any social order. (2) Each main category has several subcategories as shown in Table 1. These subcategories are conducive to productive entrepreneurship and sustainable economic growth. (3)
Admittedly, there is some overlap among these categories. For instance, enforceable property rights are a function of an accessible court system. Property rights will also be influenced by the stability of political institutions and the ability to place the appropriate checks on political agents. While recognizing this, these categories provide a framework for understanding the importance of institutions in achieving sustainable growth. In cases where payoffs to the unproductive or evasive activities are higher, we would expect the subcategories in Table 1 to be either nonexistent or distorted.
In the analysis that follows, we attempt to weave together general information regarding the institutional payoffs in Romania with original data gathered from our fieldwork in a way that illuminates the claims made earlier. This work has a similar approach to previous efforts by de Soto (1989, 2000) to understand the plight of Peru. We conducted approximately 30 in-depth, guided, face-to-face interviews with Romanian entrepreneurs and political agents in three major geographic regions of the country--Bucharest, Arad, and Olt--representing both urban and rural perspectives in roughly equal proportions. (4) Political subjects were selected on the basis of relevance and availability. Thus, those available political agents who seemed most likely to have insights related to the government's role in shaping Romania's climate of entrepreneurship received priority. Interviews with entrepreneurs were selected primarily by reference from other subjects, though some were selected at random. (5) All interviews were conducted over a two-month period from May 2003 through July 2003.
The Plight of Romania
Romania's plight effectively illustrates the problems that befall reforming nations where the payoffs for unproductive and evasive activities are relatively higher than those for productive activities. Widespread corruption and legal uncertainty, for example, continue to plague Romania. The average monthly income of citizens remains at less than $230 (World Bank 2004), and as of 2000, 44.5 percent of the population was below the poverty line (CIA World Factbook 2004). Since 1995, Romania's total Heritage Foundation/Wall Street Journal Economic Freedom Index Score has varied slightly, but each year has fallen into the category of "Mostly Unfree." (6) It is our contention that these perverse outcomes are due not to a shortage of entrepreneurs, but rather to the fact that Romanian entrepreneurs are alert to opportunities that do not yield economic growth. As an economic adviser to the Romanian president told us, "It is easier to take money from others than by producing." (7)
While studies often focus on the entrepreneurs in a specific country as a general category, in the case of Romania it is important to consider both urban and rural entrepreneurs. (8) Our fieldwork indicated that entrepreneurs in both the rural and urban setting face the same administrative and bureaucratic barriers. However, in addition to these common barriers, rural entrepreneurs face additional challenges as well. Many of the unproductive and evasive activities that occur in Romania stem from its unstable legal and judicial institutions, and the resulting rampant corruption in political institutions. We first consider unproductive activities in Romania and then turn to evasive activities.
Unproductive Entrepreneurship
The current legal environment in Romania can be seen as the cause of the rampant corruption throughout the country. The presence of excessive and uncertain regulations raises barriers to productive entrepreneurial activities. This problem is compounded by the random and ineffective enforcement of the regulations. Administrative incapacity of both the central and local governments presents a continuous problem. Appropriate resources--both financial and human--do not support the high velocity of regulatory changes, the end result being an incoherent legal framework. A study by the World Bank of corruption in Romania provides insight into the extent of the general legal environment in the country. Of the results reported, 86 percent of respondents claimed that "constant changes in laws and regulations" are a major obstacle to doing business (World Bank 2000: 11). Constantly changing laws are largely the product of "Emergency Ordinances"--immediately active executive decrees issued by the Romartian president on a frequent basis. (9) Indeed, between 1997 and 2000, 684 Emergency Ordinances were issued--nearly 43 percent of all laws created during that period. In 2000, Emergency Ordinances actually accounted for the majority (more than 56 percent) of all laws created in Romania that year. (10) As a result, it is nearly impossible to comply with the law even when one desires to do so. Recognizing this, individuals find it cheaper to ignore the law entirely. Thus, the 2003 Global Corruption Report prepared by Transparency International (2003) found that 53 percent of Romanians surveyed responded that they would "break the law to get things done." In the same report, 54 percent of the respondents said they had "trust in other people," but only 23 percent said they had "trust in institutions" that compromise society (p. 280). When asked about their perception of corruption in specific occupations, 50 percent of respondents perceived judges and lawyers to be corrupt (p. 287). (11)
The unstable legal institutions in Romania create an environment of arbitrary enforcement and widespread corruption. The World Bank (2000) study cited previously paints an accurate picture of the current situation. Approximately two-thirds of those surveyed believed that "all" or "most" public officials are corrupt (p. vi). Of those surveyed, 42 percent of households and 28 percent of established enterprises experienced corruption in a 12-month period (pp. viii, 7). Further, 50 percent of households and 44 percent of enterprises "think that bribery is part of everyday life" (p. 4). The types of corruption identified by the report include permits for building repair, construction, and real estate; driving licenses; and loan applications. In 2002, Romania was listed the third most corrupt country in Europe after Russia and Albania (Transparency International 2003).
Our fieldwork in both the urban and rural areas confirms the story told by the data just cited. The number of authorizations, approvals, and licenses varies depending on the region of the country and line of business. (12) The common thread is that in all cases investigated, the entrepreneurs indicated that regulations were both plentiful and rapidly changing. As one entrepreneur stated, "changes are so fast that no one, including public functionaries, know what the law requires on any given day." (13) This situation is strongly reinforced by the lack of an efficient court system. One entrepreneur reported that you "cannot use the state courts; they do not exist for me." (14) Another entrepreneur in Visinia Noua told us that he has never used state courts for dispute settlement because "whether you are guilty or not, you have to pay." (15)
The widespread ineffectiveness of state courts also hampers productive entrepreneurship. Specifically, the lack of an effective court system limits the expansion of one's network of clients, lenders, and suppliers. The absence of an effective court system makes it extremely difficult for entrepreneurs to extend their network beyond a few close friends and neighbors whom they know well. The fear of being cheated with little or no recourse places a strong constraint on the extent of the entrepreneur's business network. Furthermore, anyone who wants to interact with informal entrepreneurs must invest time and effort in gathering information on their credibility and trustworthiness. This increases the transaction costs of expanding one's network. The effects of this constrained network on starting, maintaining, and developing a business are apparent by the lack of economic growth in Romania. (16)
The uncertainty created by legal instability, excessive regulation, and corruption impacts entrepreneurs in a number of ways. For those who are alert to a potential business opportunity, bribes must be paid at each level of government to obtain the appropriate permits, licenses, and authorizations. Therefore, corruption is extremely damaging to economic progress on two fronts. In addition to impacting current enterprises, it also raises the cost of acting on potential business opportunities in the first place. In terms of our framework, the payoff to productive activities is lowered by the very presence of expensive bribes.
These bribes continue once the business is up and running. As one entrepreneur summed up the situation, "I'm upset about paying bribes but I've adapted to them. I want to make money." (17) Our interviews confirmed the survey results cited and concluded that entrepreneurs have come to view corruption and the uncertain legal environment as part of their daily lives.
Even after the initial bribes are paid and authorization is secured, the lack of stability and predictability of the legal environment makes it difficult to develop a long-term business plan. Given the high turnover of law, the regulations in place today may very well be drastically different in (near) future periods. This not only makes it extremely difficult for entrepreneurs to decide whether to pursue a potential profit opportunity, but also to forecast the future business environment. As one entrepreneur put it, the "law changes so often, you can't formulate a long-term business plan." (18) In addition to the aforementioned problems, the lack of stability and predictability of the legal environment also makes it difficult to obtain funding. Most formal lending institutions require some forecast of expected profitability over the long term. Generating a future forecast, however, is virtually impossible given that legal factors affecting potential profitability change frequently.
There are two ways to interpret the situation in Romania. The standard interpretation, reflected in reports by development agencies, is that there are high barriers to entrepreneurs and, hence, a shortage of entrepreneurship. Another interpretation is that entrepreneurship in Romania is flourishing. The key is the distinction we made between productive, unproductive, and evasive entrepreneurship. Productive entrepreneurship is currently stagnant in Romania. Unproductive and evasive entrepreneurship, on the other hand, are alive and well.
Given the case in changing laws and earning an income via bribes and corruption, entrepreneurial activities are directed toward these activities instead of productive ones. According to the World Bank survey (2000: x), 42 percent of enterprises responded that state officials engage in "skewing parliamentary votes in favor of certain private interests." Because changing the law is relatively easy, it makes sense for entrepreneurs to engage in activities that shift the legal environment to their own personal gain. Therefore, a large amount of resources is dedicated to rent seeking in order to obtain privileges from those in positions of power. One entrepreneur we interviewed in Visina Noua described this problem particularly well: "The sole profitable business in this environment is to have a connection in the government and make money from cheating and stealing." (19)
The situation in Romania can be viewed as a vicious circle that is a self-reinforcing, suboptimal equilibrium. One unproductive activity--for example, a new law or regulation--creates several more opportunities for other unproductive opportunities, such as inspectors using the new law to extract bribes. In fact, the constant creation of new laws and regulations often raises the returns from entering the civil service above those of entering wealth-creating enterprises. As one entrepreneur we spoke with indicated, several of his associates left successful businesses to become regulators and inspectors because they could earn more engaging in unproductive activity than in productive ones. (20) Unproductive activities thus have a negative cumulative affect, reinforcing the current stagnation that characterizes the Romanian economy.
Evasive Entrepreneurship
The widespread existence of unproductive entrepreneurship does not mean that there is a complete absence of productive activity. Our fieldwork indicated that there are many entrepreneurs engaged in productive activities. Unfortunately, many of these efforts are stifled by unproductive activities and channeled into evasive ones.
Those who undertake productive activities must invest a large amount of resources to evade the unproductive activities of others. In many cases, evasion is the only way that productive opportunities can be made profitable. Because engaging in evasive activities involves a large amount of resources, the welfare implications of these efforts constitute a significant deadweight loss for society as a whole.
Evasive entrepreneurship in Romania takes place across several margins. The most common form of evasive activity in Romania occurs via tax evasion, which is largely a result of the oblique and rapidly changing Romanian tax code. In the 2003-2004 Global Competitiveness Report (World Economic Forum 2003-2004), which ranks countries according to business leaders' beliefs about how complex and distortionary the tax system is on their business decisions, Romania ranks 100th out of 102 countries. In the same report, entrepreneurs cited tax regulations as "the most problematic factor for doing business" in Romania. While the volume of tax evasion is hard to measure, the Executive Opinion Survey, which asked Romanian business leaders about the frequency of bribes paid in connection with annual tax payments, placed Romania among the top 32 nations in this regard (World Economic Forum 2003-2004).
New labor laws (2003 Code) also make it extremely difficult to hire short-term labor and make the process of firing employees arduous. The excessive taxation of labor causes many entrepreneurs to report the minimum wage on the books while paying employees the remainder, and majority, of their salaries off the books. (21) Rapid, erratic changes in tax law make it difficult for entrepreneurs to calculate their tax liability for the purposes of forecasting future liabilities. Many understate their revenues in order to avoid paying taxes or being subject to future changes in the tax law. Tax evasion has become ingrained in the everyday life of entrepreneurs. As one entrepreneur told us, he doesn't feel guilty about evading taxes because "if you don't steal the money, state officials will." (22) Furthermore, bribes and other side payments made to avoid the unproductive activities of regulators and bureaucrats--although they constitute a major business expense (23)--cannot be formally recorded and tracked by entrepreneurs. In this environment it is extremely difficult to effectively keep accounts of the actual costs and revenues of various business activities. The result is often gross firm inefficiency.
Many entrepreneurs, especially those from rural areas, try to evade the legal process altogether. Thus, in addition to facing the same barriers as urban entrepreneurs, rural entrepreneurs face additional barriers. The main barrier is the physical distance that one has to travel to the main cities to obtain the appropriate approvals, licenses, and paperwork. As a result, many rural entrepreneurs join the underground economy or look to better-connected individuals from urban areas who specialize in obtaining the necessary forms. These middlemen are evasive entrepreneurs engaged solely in assisting productive entrepreneurs in evading the deadweight losses associated with the formal legal structure. As a result, the official and unofficial fees paid by rural entrepreneurs are comparatively higher than those paid by their urban counterparts.
For instance, one entrepreneur we interviewed cited five major licenses or permits he needed to obtain before he could open his business: rechartering his company statute, environmental protection, sanitary/animal police, fire, and worker protection standards. (24) These registrations and approvals could only be obtained by going to the Chamber of Commerce in Arad. It took him seven trips to Arad, approximately 50 miles from his home, and one and half months, to obtain all the paperwork to open his business (he estimated that each permit took about three hours to obtain and indicated that the office in Arad is only open until 11 a.m. each day). While it was possible to hire professionals to undertake all of the start-up activities, he noted that doing so was very costly. Without the funds to do this, he undertook the authorization process himself, which cost him about 10 million lei (approximately $300).
Our fieldwork indicated that excessive inspections and the need to bribe are especially high in the rural areas. Because of the relatively smaller number of enterprises and entrepreneurs in each local bureau's jurisdiction as compared with the urban areas, inspections tend to occur in these places more often. This also requires an investment on the part of entrepreneurs in building a relationship with the inspectors in order to minimize the number of bribes that need to be paid.
The rampant evasion of all laws and regulations has created a large informal sector in Romania. (25) According to the Project on Human Development, in 2003 Romania scored a 4 out of 5 for its extent of black market activity, placing the estimated size of its black market among the 50 largest underground economies in the world. (26) Because of corruption and an unstable legal system, entrepreneurs who are productive must hold many of their assets outside the law. The costs of engaging within the system are simply too high. As a result, they do not have access to the mechanisms that a formal legal system would provide them. This includes, for instance, contractual protection that is necessary to enable entrepreneurs to expand their business networks beyond a few friends and family members.
It is important to note that although the informal sector allows productive entrepreneurs to operate, it is far from perfect. In fact, there are substantial costs involved with operating in this fashion. The range of choices available to those in the informal sector, whether they are clients, suppliers, financiers, or courts, are severely limited. As already discussed, the costs involved in evading the formal system are significant. Property rights are not as strong as they could be because of a lack of formal recourse in the absence of an effective court system. There is also a limitation on how much informal businesses can expand because they must remain small in order to avoid detection. Utilizing certain credit instruments, physically expanding a business, or hiring too many workers makes detection by authorities easier and so must be avoided when productive entrepreneurs operate underground.
Conclusion
This article has argued that economic growth requires entrepreneurial alertness to be directed toward productive activities. To illustrate this argument, Romania was analyzed as a case where the payoff to unproductive and evasive activities is relatively higher as compared with productive activities. Given this, it is possible to put forth some general guidelines for the achievement of economic progress.
First, entrepreneurship is omnipresent. Entrepreneurs are present in all settings. Cultural explanations for a lack of entrepreneurship overlook what people have in common--namely, alertness for profit and ways to improve their general situations. Underdeveloped nations do not lack entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurial activities exist but are not being directed toward productive ends conducive to economic progress.
Second, government policy cannot create entrepreneurship. Instead, emphasis should be placed on creating a general institutional framework that makes the payoffs to productive entrepreneurship high relative to unproductive and evasive activities. Resources should not be allocated to "encouraging" or "training" entrepreneurs, but in developing the necessary institutional context to allow productive activities to come to the forefront.
Third, transparency and accountability are critical for reform. In many cases, the lack of transparency and accountability allows officials to abuse the law for personal reasons. One key mechanism for creating transparency is a free media industry, which serves as a check on those in positions of power to abuse the political and legal institutions (Coyne and Leeson 2004). Increased transparency and accountability reduce the payoff to unproductive activities.
Finally, reform needs to be decentralized. Currently, the national government controls all reform efforts and neglects the unique situation of rural entrepreneurs. Reform efforts should be decentralized to the local level so that those who truly understand these challenges are involved in the reform process.
As economics and history teach us, these guidelines present the best opportunity for overcoming the plight of underdeveloped nations.
TABLE 1 A SOCIAL ORDER CONDUCIVE TO PRODUCTIVE ENTREPRENEURSHIP Economic Political Legal Institutions Institutions Institutions Private Property Checks and Balances Rule of Law Well-defined Federalism Generality Enforceable Fiscal Stability Freedom to contract Monetary Predictability Capital Markets Accountability Independent Open Trade Transparency judiciary Low Barriers to Entry Functional and and Exit Assessible Courts
(1) This fieldwork was conducted by the authors under the auspices of a project considering barriers to entrepreneurship for the U.S. Agency for International Development.
(2) Although not our focus here, informal institutions including norms, values, and social capital that underpin these formal institutions are also critical for fostering entrepreneurship.
(3) For more on the institutions necessary for a stable social order and economic growth, see Barro (1999); Boettke and Coyne (2003); Gwartney, Lawson, and Holcombe (1999); Harper (2004); and Scully (1988, 1992).
(4) Bucharest is the capital city of Romania and provides a sample of entrepreneurs in the urban environment. Our interviews of rural entrepreneurs took place in the village of Busteni, in Arad County in the Western Carpathians, and in Visina Noua, in Olt County in the Danube plain. Both authors were present for all interviews.
(5) Subjects ranged in age from 29 to approximately 65 and included both men and women.
(6) For the report on Romania, see http://cf.heritage.org/index2004test/country2.cfm? id=Romania.
(7) Interview with Vladimir Pasti, Bucharest, 5/26/03.
(8) Nearly half (about 45 percent) of the Romanian population lives in rural areas (United Nations 2004). As of 2000, agriculture employed 41 percent of the total employed populace with 31 percent in services and 27 percent in industry. Nevertheless, agricultural output accounts for only 13 percent of Romanian GDP (CIA World Factbook 2004).
(9) We discussed the problem of "Emergency Ordinances" with Cristian Boureanu, former adviser to the minister of finance, Bucharest, 5/28/03, and with Entrepreneur 13, Visina Noua, 6/1/03.
(10) Romanian Ministry of Justice Legislative Database available at: www.guv.ro; see also, Stan (2002).
(11) Percentage of people responding "almost all of them are involved" or "most of them are involved."
(12) The 2004 Index of Economic Freedom quotes the Financial Times as saying: "It takes anything from 49 to 102 days to register a new company: 83 pages of forms have to be completed, weighing half a kilo.... Small to medium-sized enterprises have between 11 and 23 inspections a year.... A business start-up needs between 23 and 29 authorizations and approvals" (Miles, Feulner, O'Grady 2004: 338).
(13) Interview with Entrepreneur 7, Bucharest 5/27/03.
(14) Interview with Entrepreneur 1, Bucharest, 5/19/03.
(15) Interview with Entrepreneur 13, Visina Noua, 6/1/03.
(16) The state of courts and the impact on the entrepreneurial process were discussed in interviews with Entrepreneur 1, Bucharest, 5/19/03; Entrepreneur 4, Bucharest, 5/22/03; Entrepreneur 7, Bucharest, 5/27/03; Entrepreneur 8, Bucharest, 5/27/03; Cristian Boureanu, Bucharest, 5/28/03; Entrepreneur 13, Visina Noua, 6/1/03; Entrepreneur 16, Visina Noua, 6/2/03; and Entrepreneur 18, Visina Noua, 6/3/03.
(17) Interview with Entrepreneur 1, Bucharest, 5/19/03.
(18) Interview with Entrepreneur 1, Bucharest, 5/19/03.
(19) Interview with Entrepreneur 16, Visina Noua, 6/2/08.
(20) Interview with Entrepreneur 1, Bucharest, 5/22/03.
(21) The impact of tax law and tax evasion on the entrepreneurial process was discussed in interviews with Entrepreneur 1, Bucharest, 5/19/03; Entrepreneur 7, Bucharest, 5/27/03; Entrepreneur 8, Bucharest, 5/27/03; Entrepreneur 12, Visina Noua, 6/1/03; Entrepreneur 13, Visina Noua, 6/1/03; Entrepreneur 16, Visina Noua, 6/2/03; Entrepreneur 18, Visina Noua, 6/3/03; and Entrepreneur 26, Visina Noua, 6/3/03.
(22) Interview with Entrepreneur 1, Bucharest, 5/19/03.
(23) According to the Global Competitiveness Report (2003-2004), Romania ranked 70th out of 102 countries in terms of paying bribes connected to annum tax payments.
(24) Interview with Entrepreneur 24, Buteni, 6/14/03.
(25) Romania received a score of 4 (with "1" being the best and "5" being the worst) in the 2004 Index of Economic Freedom in the category of "Informal Market."
(26) Report available at http://humandevelopment.bu.edu/use_exsisting_index/ show_aggregate.elm?index_id=295&data_type=1.
References
Barro, R. J. (1999) Determinants of Economic Growth. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Baumol, W. J. (1990) "Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive and Destructive." Journal of Political Economy 98 (5): 893-921.
--(2002) The Free-Market Innovation Machine. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Boettke, P. J., and Coyne, C. J. (2004) "Entrepreneurship and Development: Cause or Consequence?" Advances in Austrian Economics 6: 67-88.
Brenner, R. (1985) Betting on Ideas: Wars, Invention, Inflation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
CIA World Factbook (2004) www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook.
Coyne, C. J., and Leeson, P. T. (2004) "Read All About It! Understanding the Role of Media in Economic Development." Kyklos 57: 21-44.
de Soto, H. (1989) The Other Path. New York: Basic Books.
--(2000) The Mystery of Capital. New York: Basic Books.
Gwartney, J.; Lawson, R.; and Holcombe, R. (1999) "Economic Freedom and the Environment for Economic Growth." Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 155: 643-63.
Harper, D.A. (2004) Foundations of Entrepreneurship and Economic Development. New York: Routledge.
Kirzner, I. M. (1973) Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
--(1985) Discovery and the Capitalist Process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Leff, N. (1979) "Entrepreneurship and Economic Development: The Problem Revisited." Journal of Economic Literature 17: 46-64.
Miles, M. A.; Feulner; E. J., and O'Grady, M. A. (2004) 2004 Index of Economic Freedom. New York: Heritage Foundation and Dow Jones.
Mokyr, J. (1990) The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. New York: Oxford University Press.
OECD (1998) "Fostering Entrepreneurship" (www1.oecd.org/publications/ Pol_brief/1998/9809-eng.htm).
Reynolds, P. D.; Hay, M.; and Camp, M. S. (1999) Global Entrepreneurship Monitor Report. Kansas City: E. M. Kauffmann Foundation.
Rothbard, M. N. ([1962] 1993) Man, Economy and State. Auburn, Ala.: The Ludwig von Mises Institute.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1950) Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper and Bros.
--(1961) The Theory of Economic Development. New York: Oxford University Press.
Scully, G. W. (1988) "The Institutional Framework and Economic Development." Journal of Political Economy 96: 652-62.
--(1992) Constitutional Environments and Economic Growth. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Stan, L. (2002) "Comparing Regime Governance: A Case Study." Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics 18: 77-109.
Transparency International (2003) Global Corruption Report 2003. Berlin: Transparency International/Profile Books. Report available at: www. globalcorruptionreport.org/download/gcr2003/24_Data_and_research.pdf.
United Nations (2004) World Urbanization Prospects: The 2003 Revision Population Database. Available at: http://esa.un.org/unup/.
World Bank (2000) "Diagnostic Surveys of Corruption in Romania." Available at www.worldbank.org.ro/ECA/Romania.nsf/ECADocByUnid/ 85256B6E005A94B285256B13007CB509?Opendocument.
--(2004) World Development Indicators 2004. Washington: World Bank.
World Economic Forum (2003-2004) The Global Competitiveness Report 2003-2004. Geneva: World Economic Forum.
Christopher J. Coyne is the H. B. Earhart Fellow and Peter T. Leeson is the Oloffson Weaver Fellow in the Department of Economies at George Mason University. Both authors are also Research Scholars in the Social Change Group at the Mercatus Center. Leeson was a Visiting Fellow in Political Economy and Government at Harvard University at the time this research was written. The authors gratefully acknowledge financial assistance from the U.S. Agency for International Development and the Mercatus Center.